|
You are here:
Home
> February 2007 editorial a
web journal of urban and political affairs
|
|
|
Editorial: February 2007
Workers flee Sydney's unaffordable
housing The most widely cited measures of home loan affordability in Australia are the Real Estate Institute of Australia home loan affordability indicator, the Commonwealth Bank of Australia-Housing Industry Association housing affordability index, and the BIS Shrapnel home loan affordability index. A Reserve Bank research note on these measures last November said ‘there has been an appreciable deterioration in affordability since 2001’. It was considered ‘significant that in 2006 the affordability indicator had fallen to a level comparable to that reached in 1989, despite the fact that interest rates in 2006 have been very much lower than they were in 1989’. The news is no better for renters. Sydney’s rental vacancy rate is running at 1.5 per cent, the lowest in 20 years. And rents are predicted to rise by 20 per cent this year. Landlords never had it so good. Few now deny that housing affordability is a serious social problem, particularly in our larger cities. However, there is heated disagreement about its causes, and how to respond. In general terms, the debate is between those who contend that house prices are essentially cyclical and others who argue that they reflect structural distortions. The NSW Government, for example, views Sydney’s current level of affordability as a function of last year’s interest rate hikes. These have bumped up borrower repayments and flattened the property market by scaring off investors. Predictably, the NSW Opposition says state-based property taxes (especially land tax) and levies are the killers. The underlying assumption, in both cases, is that property markets are inherently cyclical, so conditions for buyers and renters will improve once monetary policy is loosened or tax rates are adjusted. The cyclical explanation is attractive to those with a vested interest in the prevailing system of land zoning, mortgage lending and property taxation. Left-leaning academics and environmentalists, who harp on about the boom-and-bust pattern of capital accumulation, tag along. Monetary policy, taxes and levies do have a significant impact on affordability. The federal government can’t just blame the states in this respect. But the factors driving housing values are more diverse, complex and interrelated than the cyclical interpretation suggests. A complete explanation must also focus on the supply side of the equation, particularly the supply of land, which - for many - is the real lynchpin of the prevailing system. One leading member of Australia’s structural camp, Alan Moran of the Institute of Public Affairs, estimated that ‘the land component, which in 1976-77 comprised 32 per cent of a new home in Sydney, in 2005 comprised 62 per cent’. Moran is in no doubt that this escalation relates ‘to the squeeze on land availability originated in misplaced desires to prevent “urban sprawl”’, while noting that ‘building costs have been stable’. If land prices remained stable or increased only at the rate of underlying inflation, says Moran, ‘average new house prices would have been 40 per cent lower than is presently observed’. This is a powerful point considering that the median house price in Sydney was $520,300 in September 2006. Reports and studies highlighting the impact of land supply policies on affordability are starting to flow from housing and property industry associations and analysts. The most influential catalyst for discussion remains the Annual Demographia International Housing Affordability Survey, the third edition of which was released last month. The survey measures affordability across 159 markets in Australia, Canada, Ireland, New Zealand, the United Kingdom and the United States by means of the ‘median multiple’ (median house price divided by median annual household income). The benchmark for affordability is a multiple of 3.0, where the median house price is three times the median household income. Consequently, the survey assigns Sydney (8.5), Melbourne (6.6) and Perth (8.0) to the category ‘severely unaffordable’ (5.1 and over). Sydney is the eighth most unaffordable market surveyed, less affordable than New York and London. Australia’s national median multiple is 6.6, more than double the affordable benchmark. The survey’s strength lies in its comparative methodology. It’s hard to dispute a consistent pattern emerging from so many markets with varying population sizes, histories, locations, industrial and economic orientations, interest rate regimes and taxation arrangements. In contrast to the dire Australian findings, 42 markets are assigned to the ‘affordable’ category, including sizeable American and Canadian cities like Atlanta, Detroit, Dallas, Houston, Pittsburgh, Quebec and Ottawa. The survey’s message is clear, and consistent with Moran’s: Research in the surveyed nations identifies the cause - the housing cost escalation is principally the result of supply factors. Where there are significant constraints on the supply of land for residential development, housing inflation has occurred. Where there are no such constraints, housing cost inflation has not occurred. Demand does not raise prices by itself. Demand can only raise prices where there is insufficient supply. This conclusion undermines a popular Australian criticism of the structural or land supply explanation, namely that historically low interest rates in the early 2000s - which boosted the purchasing power of home buyers by 60 per cent, according to Rory Robertson - drove up demand and prices. The NSW Government and some media elements dismissed the survey on this ground. The Government also thought Sydney’s dismal ranking was misleading, since the ‘study included expensive harbourside areas’. This objection would have more substance if the survey used mean rather than median prices - median values, unlike means, are barely affected by a few extreme observations. As the survey points out, the median multiple has been recommended by the World Bank and the United Nations as a tool for evaluating urban markets. On the strength of his paper, Thinking About the Big Drop in Australian Housing Affordability, Robertson was trotted out by the Fairfax newspapers to trample on the structural or land supply perspective. One Sydney Morning Herald article featured his assertion that releasing more land on the outskirts will do nothing to improve affordability. Desirable inner Sydney suburbs like Bondi, Bellevue Hill, Bronte, Mosman and Paddington, he said, would remain beyond the reach of most first home buyers. This is a statement of the obvious, of course, and beside the point. Land releases improve affordability on fringe greenfields sites - where a large proportion, probably a majority, of low to middle income couples with children are willing to live. Shortly afterwards, the Australian Financial Review quoted him deriding the Demographia survey because the ‘the 26 most-expensive cities were high demand locations with a “large, sexy and high profile”’. In contrast, said Robertson, the affordable cities ‘were generally low-demand locations’, like Fort Wayne and other US cities which ‘were actually shrinking in size, such as Youngstown, Buffalo, Dayton, Rochester, Akron and Toledo’. He neglects to mention, though, that the affordable category also includes the booming cities of Atlanta, Dallas, Pittsburgh and Houston. The NSW Government is not oblivious to the need for more residential lots on greenfields sites, and its comprehensive City of Cities plan earmarks two substantial north-western and south-western ‘growth centres’ for residential development. But the plan envisages that over the next 25 years only 30 to 40 per cent of Sydney's new housing (160,000 lots) will be built in these centres, while the balance will be assigned to higher density developments in the city's established inner suburbs. This is unlikely to have much impact on the affordability problem, however. In this respect at least, Robertson is correct. Yet the Government rejects expanded land supply as a solution to Sydney’s housing crisis, claiming that although 26,000 lots (including 17,000 rezoned by the Government last year) are currently available, there is simply no demand from developers and buyers in the weak property market. This reflects a narrow cyclical view of the market, however, and ignores the relationship between demand and prices. If lots were more freely available, their price would be lower and demand higher. Housing affordability is on the agenda. But until planners and policymakers break free of their limited cyclical perspective, we aren’t likely to see more than stopgap proposals to increase the first home owners grant, cut taxes and stamp duty, increase the stock of public housing and rent relief - all of which are helpful but amount to little more than tinkering around the edges. Freeing up the land supply disturbs powerful interests, who will resort to flawed economic analysis, and fears of social dysfunction and environmental degradation, including the prospect that suburban expansion will increase carbon emissions. All of these grounds are proved baseless on closer scrutiny. They will be examined in future editions of The New City.
This
editorial was republished by
On Line Opinion,
Australia's e-journal of social and political debate.
m
e |
|
|